The Late, Late Show: How a Priority Flight System Can Reduce the Cost of Air Traffic Delays

Similar documents
Jet Fuel Hedging, Operational Efficiency Improvement and Carbon Tax

Dynamic Revenue Management in Airline Alliances

The Future of Business Air Travel

EFFECTIVENESS OF A BARGE-BASED BALLAST WATER TREATMENT SYSTEM FOR MULTI-TERMINAL PORTS

Meeting: OPS.001 Rulemaking Group Meeting Apr. 24 & 26, 2007 and Non-commercial Operations Sub-group Meeting Apr. 24 & 25, 2007

MERCHANT SHIPPING (MANNING AND STCW) REGULATIONS

First Class Rank. Workbook. Scout s Name:

Using [3.3] indicate whether there are any hot deserts located near the: a

MERCHANT SHIPPING (SURVEY AND CERTIFICATION) REGULATIONS

Merchant Shipping (Fees) Regulations 2017 MERCHANT SHIPPING (FEES) REGULATIONS 2017

Merchant Shipping (Control of Harmful Anti-Fouling Systems) Order 2014 Article 1

ARMATA To prevent punching failure of concrete slabs. Version: AE, SA 08/2017. Technical Manual

AIR NAVIGATION (RESTRICTION OF FLYING) (TT RACES) REGULATIONS 2017

DEVELOPMENT CONCEPT OF THE DUBROVNIK PASSENGER PORT FOR ACCOMMODATION OF LARGE CRUISE VESSELS

BEFORE THE FEDERAL AVIATION ADMINISTRATION U.S. DEPARTMENT OF TRANSPORTATION WASHINGTON, D.C. COMMENTS OF CANADIAN AIRLINES INTERNATIONAL LTD.

Chapter 1 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

Impact of Landing Fee Policy on Airlines Service Decisions, Financial Performance and Airport Congestion

Titanic! Teacher s notes

Merchant Shipping (MARPOL Annex V) Order 2014 MERCHANT SHIPPING (MARPOL ANNEX V PREVENTION OF POLLUTION BY GARBAGE) ORDER 2014

Noise Exposure Map Update Louisville International Airport

UC Berkeley Working Papers

Explanatory Memorandum

AUSTRALIA COAST TO COAST APRIL 2016 ESCAPE T EVERYDAY

Fewer air traffic delays in the summer of 2001

CODNOR PARISH COUNCIL. Minutes of the Meeting of the Codnor Parish Council held in Peverel House, Mill Lane, Codnor

A COGNITIVE CONSTRUCTIONIST

Collaborative Decision Making By: Michael Wambsganss 10/25/2006

Your Service Documentation. Automechanika Frankfurt / REIFEN 2018

Spatial Displacement and Sustainable Heritage Tourism

Case Study 2. Low-Cost Carriers

Response to Docket No. FAA , Voluntary Disclosure Reporting Program, published in the Federal Register on 19 March 2009

An Econometric Study of Flight Delay Causes at O Hare International Airport Nathan Daniel Boettcher, Dr. Don Thompson*

Airline Schedule Development Overview Dr. Peter Belobaba

Schedule Compression by Fair Allocation Methods

Department of Transportation, Federal Aviation Administration (FAA). SUMMARY: Under this notice, the FAA announces the submission deadline of

WEB APPENDIX D CAPACITY PLANNING AND PRICING AGAINST A LOW-COST COMPETITOR: A CASE STUDY OF PIEDMONT AIRLINES AND PEOPLE EXPRESS

Abstract. Introduction

FACT SHEET Downtown Obstructions and Future Air Service for San José and Silicon Valley

CITY OF NEWPORT AND PORT OF ASTORIA REQUEST FOR PROPOSALS -- SCHEDULED AIRLINE SERVICE BASIC INFORMATION

BEFORE THE DEPARTMENT OF TRANSPORTATION WASHINGTON, D.C.

We design our wood-burning stoves with insight and respect for craftsmanship. Contents. DK Lemvig

BEFORE THE DEPARTMENT OF TRANSPORTATION OFFICE OF AVIATION ENFORCEMENT AND PROCEEDINGS WASHINGTON, D.C.

Hydrological Studies of the Slims River, Yukon, June-August 1970

Cleveland Hopkins International Airport Preliminary Merger Analysis

REVIEW OF THE STATE EXECUTIVE AIRCRAFT POOL

Applying Integer Linear Programming to the Fleet Assignment Problem

BEFORE THE DEPARTMENT OF TRANSPORTATION WASHINGTON, DC ANSWER OF JETBLUE AIRWAYS CORPORATION TO APPLICATION OF AMERICA WEST AIRLINES, INC.

OPTIMAL PUSHBACK TIME WITH EXISTING UNCERTAINTIES AT BUSY AIRPORT

Given the challenges, airlines would far prefer to have ample capacity and no slot constraints.

International Civil Aviation Organization WORLDWIDE AIR TRANSPORT CONFERENCE (ATCONF) SIXTH MEETING. Montréal, 18 to 22 March 2013

Finance and Implementation

BEFORE THE U.S. DEPARTMENT OF TRANSPORTATION FEDERAL AVIATION ADMINISTRATION WASHINGTON, D.C. COMMENTS OF WESTJET

DEVELOPMENT OF TOE MIDFIELD TERMINAL IROJECT CAPACITY ENHANCEMENT REPORT DEPARTMENT OF AVIATION TOM FOERSTER CHAIRMAN BARBARA HAFER COMMISSIONER

SUMMARY OF RBVISIONS To FAv{ Approved ROTORCRAFT FLIGHT II{ANUAL For Model 269C

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA DEPARTMENT OF TRANSPORTATION OFFICE OF AVIATION ENFORCEMENT AND PROCEEDINGS WASHINGTON, DC. March 4, 2015

Aviation Insights No. 8

We ve been working to position the region to benefit from the Dulles expansion capacity. I ll touch on just a few of the items.

Submitted Electronically to the Federal erulemaking Portal:

June 12, Dear Administrator Pekoske,

American Airlines Next Top Model

Ozaukee County Transit Development Plan

[Docket No. FAA ; Directorate Identifier 2012-NM-206-AD; Amendment

Federal Subsidies to Passenger Transportation December 2004

REPORTS ON ACTS OF PIRACY AND ARMED ROBBERY AGAINST SHIPS. Third quarterly report (July to, and including, September 2005)

Transfer Scheduling and Control to Reduce Passenger Waiting Time

Submitted by the Aviation Suppliers Association 2233 Wisconsin Ave, NW, Suite 503 Washington, DC 20007

M ESSAGE FROM THE C HAIR

THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF NEW CONNECTIONS TO CHINA

APPENDIX J MODIFICATIONS PERFORMED TO THE TOR

2009 Muskoka Airport Economic Impact Study

INCENTIVE PROGRAM

Gerry Laderman SVP Finance, Procurement and Treasurer

A Conversation with... Brett Godfrey, CEO, Virgin Blue

CUSTOMS AND BORDER PROTECTION (CBP) STAFFING

Policy Regarding Airport Rates and Charges

AIR TRANSPORT MANAGEMENT Universidade Lusofona January 2008

BEFORE THE UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF TRANSPORTAION WASHINGTON, D.C. 14 CFR Parts 234, 244, 250, 253, 259 and 399 COMMENTS OF FARELOGIX, INC.

PRAJWAL KHADGI Department of Industrial and Systems Engineering Northern Illinois University DeKalb, Illinois, USA

SMS HAZARD ANALYSIS AT A UNIVERSITY FLIGHT SCHOOL

TOWN HERALD. Legacy Park

Office of Program Policy Analysis And Government Accountability

[Docket No. FAA ; Directorate Identifier 2005-NM-056-AD; Amendment ; AD ]

SUPERSEDED. [Docket No NM-217-AD; Amendment ; AD ]

Airline Passenger Safety or Customer Satisfaction?

Current Activities Affecting FAA ADs

Factorial Study on Airport Delay for Flight Scheduling Process

Comments on the Draft Environmental Impact Report (DEIR) of the LAX Landside Access Modernization Program (LAMP)

Overview of PODS Consortium Research

Appendix 9. Impacts on Great Western Main Line. Prepared by Christopher Stokes

Alternative solutions to airport saturation: simulation models applied to congested airports. March 2017

sdrftsdfsdfsdfsdw Comment on the draft WA State Aviation Strategy

Airports Commission. Discussion Paper 04: Airport Operational Models. Response from the British Air Transport Association (BATA) June 2013

Why Airline Antitrust Immunity Benefits Consumers

Report of the Rolling Spike Task Force

AGENDA GUEMES ISLAND FERRY OPERATIONS PUBLIC FORUM

Appendix B Ultimate Airport Capacity and Delay Simulation Modeling Analysis

Bumpy Skies. Report - October 2002

Route Planning and Profit Evaluation Dr. Peter Belobaba

A. CONCLUSIONS OF THE FGEIS

SAMTRANS TITLE VI STANDARDS AND POLICIES

Transcription:

14 TRANSPORTATION RESEARCH RECORD 1161 The Late, Late Show: How a Priority Flight System Can Redue the Cost of Air Traffi Delays CHRISTOPHER J. MAYER Air traffi delays, although not new, have beome inreasingly worse in the 198s and are now estimated to ost over $2 billion a year. A system of using Hight prlorltles to make more preditable flight shedules Is suggested, a system that ould save onsumers tens of millions of hours in travel time and produe millions more on-time arrivals. Suh a system would allow onsumers to hoose among different priorities of servie, suh as express flights versus regular Hlghts, with fare differenes reheting the differenes in Hight time. Airlines would be better able to use their planes, gates, and rews beause Hight shedules would be more preditable. All of this would our without arbitrary restritions on apaity and In a system that would enourage airlines to ompete with on-time performane. A repeated aution ould be used to distribute the priorities ompetitively and effiiently. Reduing the tiket tax by the revenue raised In this aution would leave average tiket pries unhanged. This researh simulates how suh a system would operate at Chiago's O'Hare Airport, using several different priority plans. With this system delays at O'Hare alone an be ut by 3.5 million hr a year. This figure Is a lower bound for savings, beause It does not inlude the savings to airlines or other related businesses and does not aount for benefits suh as a more preditable system. Although additional researh Is ertainly required, a priority system seems to hold signifiant potential for alleviating muh of the ost of air traffi ongestion. "The Late, Late Show-Airline delays are bad-and they are going to get worse," aording to the U.S. News and World Report (J). A Wall Street Journal headline read, "Hurry Up and Wait: Airline Delays Bring Gripes-And Lots of Exuses" (2). The newspaper further reported, "Cosmeti Change: Airlines' Pledge To Redue Delays May Be Illusory" (3). Although travel delays are not new, the dramati inrease in their number has attrated muh media attention. In this paper a priority system is proposed that would make delays more preditable and allow onsumers to hoose among several probabilities of delay as they now hoose between levels of servie (i.e., first lass, business lass, or oah lass). This method will also have the potential to save onsumers tens of millions of travel hours, allow airlines to have better ontrol of their shedules at a lower ost per seat, and remove signifiant publi pressure from the FAA. The history of the delay problem is often traed to two events: airline deregulation in the late 197s and the strike by Department of Eonomis, Massahusetts Institute of Tehnology, 5 Memorial Drive, Cambridge, Mass. 2139. air traffi ontrollers in 1981. Deregulation removed flight routes from the government's ontrol, allowing airlines almost omplete freedom to shedule flights. The air traffi ontrollers strike ut bak on the number of adequately trained ontrollers and, some laim, still affets the apaity of the air traffi ontrol system. Responsibility for the delays that followed these two events has been hotly debated. Some blame the FAA for not rehiring the fired ontrollers. The FAA laims that the airlines are to blame beause they bunh flights, reating unrealisti shedules that exeed apaity at many airports. The airlines often blame the publi for all wanting to fly at the same time and laim that any airline that unilaterally resheduled flights would ommit ompetitive suiide. Meanwhile the delay problem ontinues to worsen, at an inreasing ost to all involved. Businessmen and frequent flyers spend more and more time traveling and less time working. The airlines' inreased use of the hub-and-spoke system has aused many more missed onnetions and unplanned overnight stays. Delays raise the labor osts of airlines and ause them to use their apital ineffiiently (e.g., for gate spae and airraft). The Air Transport Assoiation (ATA), a trade assoiation for the major airlines, estimated that these annual osts exeed $2 billion. The U.S. Department of Transportation (DOT) has reently fored airlines at four major airports to amend their timetables to redue flight delays. [By April l, 1988, flights at the four airports must operate within 3 min of published shedules at iast 75 perent of the time (4).] This hange, as Congressman Pete DeFazio noted, makes shedules more preditable for the onsumer, but has little substane (3). Flights do not arrive more quikly than before this ruling; airlines simply add more time to the shedules of existing flights. Without strutural or proedural hanges in the way the air traffi ontrol system operates, ongestion will ontinue and air travel will still be errati and time-onsuming. Many people have proposed other solutions to the urrent problem. Some have reommended applying "lassial" eonomis to the problem (i.e., treating the delays as exess demand for sare resoures). This reasoning led to the system of slot ontrol that the FAA is testing at four airports-national Airport in Washington, D.C.; O'Hare in Chiago; and Kennedy and LaGuardia in New York. Slot ontrol, however, has not managed to redue delays greatly at these airports; they are still among the most ongested in the system. (Furthermore, no one knows what the right number of slots is for any airport.) Other

15 Mayer "market" solutions range from reommendations to raise the landing fees during ongested times to the ATA reommendation to make the FAA a private organization. (The ATA proposal presumes that a private FAA would be free of bureaurati restraints and would use market mehanisms and greater investment to reate a more effiient air traffi ontrol system.) Others have onluded that deregulation has failed and that regulations are neessary. Currently proposed bills in Congress would require all airlines to publiize various types of servie information and would fine airlines that have "unrealisti" shedules. Still others support the urrent DOT poliy that gives airlines exemption from antitrust laws to oordinate their shedules and eliminate the bunhing that aounts for many delays. The third lass of solutions would inrease the apaity of the system. Congress is now releasing the funds in the Airport Trust Fund to build newer and larger airports, hire more air traffi ontrollers, and modernize the whole system. Some have suggested that Congress spend even more. A few believe that some urrent FAA safety margins are too restritive and that hanging the safety margins would inrease the apaity of the air traffi ontrol system. When the problem of delays is onsidered, however, the optimal solution should address many onerns. Clearly safety should be proteted with any proposal. The ideal solution should also produe soially optimal results and, if possible, benefit all parties involved. Competition must also be preserved. Of ourse, the solution should be politially feasible. Finally, some short-term benefit (i.e., some immediate relief from delays) is very important. Many of the earlier solutions fell short of this ideal. The market solutions, as a group, ertainly have potential for soial gains, but are often politially infeasible, potentially nonompetitive, and too ompliated to be realisti. (For example, an optimal landing fee to relieve ongestion was proposed that would hange depending on the weather.) Reregulation also has its problems. It ould likely restrit ompetition, raise fares, and negate some of the soial gains made from deregulation. Inreasing apaity would ertainly help to solve the delay problem, but is a long-term venture that is being held up beause of budget onstraints. Even without budget onstraints, there is no good way lo determine what the optimal investment in the air traffi ontrol system should be. Finally, there is often loal opposition to expansion and muh politial opposition to rehiring the fired air traffi ontrollers. A NEW IDEA: ATTACH PRIORITIES TO FLIGHTS In this paper a very diffei;enl strategy to attak the delay problem is analyzed: attahing priorities to flights. Although this onept arries its own potential implementation problems, whih will be addressed later, these problems appear to be solvable. For now, the more fundamental questions will be disussed: how might suh a plan work and what are its potential gains? A system of priorities is a market-based alternative to reregulation of the airline industry. It reates more arefully defined property rights, whereas the urrent system reates only ambiguous ones. A landing slot arries the right to land at an airport-a priority gives the additional right of landing before other users of lower priority. Indeed, ineffiient ongestion ould not our if a fully defined system of property rights existed, beause market transations would readily eliminate undesirable ongestion. How the Priority System Would Funtion Currently all flights are treated equally. A fully loaded 747 is given the same probability of delay as a partly filled 737 with one-tenth the number of passengers, even though the osts of delaying the former greatly exeed the osts of delaying the latter. A system of priorities ould allow airlines to separate travelers aording to the value of their time, putting those with a high value of time (e.g., businessmen or other frequent fliers) on express flights and those with a lower value of time (e.g., vaationers) on regular flights. As odd as this might seem, it is similar to the struture of train servie in Japan, Italy, and Frane, where travelers pay a premium for express servie. Amerian Airlines Chairman Robert Crandall has publily advoated suh a system. A system of priorities allows the air traffi ontrol system to differentiate among airraft. This would not neessarily mean that larger airraft would always have 'priority over smaller airraft. Highest priorities should go to the most valuable users. As will be disussed later, an aution would provide an eonomially effiient way to distribute priorities to the most valuable users of an airport. In addition, a system of priorities would potentially allow airlines to redue their per-seal osts. For example, larger airraft ould be used on the express routes, so these airraft would reeive fewer delays and be used for more flights. Beause express flights with larger, more expensive rews would reeive fewer delays, labor osts would also fall. These gains would result in lower overall tiket pries. How the FAA Handles Congestion: Central Flow Control An brief explanation of how the FAA deals with air traffi ongestion will also show that the priority system proposed is very ompatible with urrent operating proedure and would not require a large-sale retraining of ontrollers. The FAA Central Flow Control Offie in Washington, D.C., regulates ongestion throughout the ountry. Initially, flow ontrol was reated lo derease the fuel osts of airplanes flying in lengthy holding patterns while waiting to land Sine then, safety and inreased ongestion have further supported the need for flow ontrol, by whih airport ongestion is antiipated and demand is regulated by delaying planes from taking off until there is spae for them to land. Flow ontrol aomplishes this by using both omputers and staff. There is always a weather foreaster on site to help predit where and when the weather will onstrain apaity. The ontrollers in flow ontrol then disuss these foreasts with both loal and regional air traffi ontrollers as well as with airline offiials to get a good estimate of the future apaity at the target airport. This is usually done 4 hr before the expeted ongestion. Then the ontroller enters this estimate into a omputer and runs a program to determine gate holds. This

16 program looks at the intended arrival time of all sheduled servie at the target airport and in an unbiased, random fashion delays the departure time of some airraft to give an even flow of traffi into the airport. This ontrolled flow also ensures that plans will have minimal airborne holds before landing. It is important to note that these programs are frequently run when airports have perfetly lear weather, beause flight bunhing auses everyday ongestion. The flow ontrol mehanisms are unpreditable and unontrollable, so neither the airlines nor the publi has advane warning about whih flights will be delayed. Adding a system of priorities would inrease the information to all involved parties. It would require only a minimal hange in the software to add priority as another parameter in the flow-ontrol program. A priority system would only apply to airraft before they take off. Some have suggested that the system ontinue while flights are in the air. This is infeasible beause it would require retraining air traffi ontrollers at a time when there are not enough of them. Treating airraft differently in the air ould also pose a severe satety hazard. SIMULATION OF AIRPORT WITH PRIORITY SYSTEM: 47 DAYS AT O'HARE An important question is, How might suh a system funtion and how would it ompare with the urrent operating system? A omputer simulation has been devised to help understand how suh a system might work and to help predit any soial gains that might be realized. The simulation was designed to test a priority system at a single airport using atual flight data and weather onditions. Chiago's O'Hare Airport was hosen for several important reasons. First, it is an example of a fully saturated airport that, even with slot ontrol, has serious ongestion problems and thus has potential for signifiant improvement. Next, very aurate weather and landing data are available that show the atual onstraints on apaity by hour for 47 days during the first 6 months of 1987. Finally, O'Hare has been losely studied by FAA to determine the auses of delays there. How the Simulation Works The simulation does not provide minute-to-minute auray, beause suh a system would be too preise to be realisti. Instead it looks at the apaity and sheduling at O'Hare in 15- min intervals, dealing with a 14-hr "window" of flights from 7: a.m. to 9: p.m. The simulation also assumes that there are no anellations or mehanial delays and that all flights are able to leave at their appointed times. For example, assume that between 9: and 9:14 a.m. 3 flights are sheduled to arrive at O'Hare, but there is apaity for only 25 flights. Assume that these flights have the following priorities attahed to them: 5 priority-one flights, 7 priority-two flights, 14 priority-three flights, and 4 priority-four flights. The simulation would lear all priority-one and -two flights to land. Priority-four flights would all be delayed 15 min and plaed in the 9:15-9:29 a.m. time slot. One of the priority-three flights would be randomly hosen to be delayed with the priority-four flights; the rest would be leared to land. The delayed flights in the new time slot would be treated as other flights of the same TRANSPORTATION RESEARCH RECORD 1161 priority in that slot. (Later different plans will be disussed to determine whether flights should be given a higher priority after a ertain amount of delay.) This simulation, although simple, is not as unrealisti as it might seem. Adding flight anellations, for example, should not hange the results muh. [Even Continental Airlines, onsidered by some to be the most unpreditable airline, anels about 1 perent of its flights (5).] Small departure or mehanial delays should also have little effet on auray beause the simulation uses 15-min slots. Finally, it is reognized that sheduled arrival times refer to arrival at the gate, not the runway. However, one ould simply subtrat 5 or 1 min from the arrival time to aount for taxiing time and not disturb the results. Certainly the simulation does not assess how the priority system would affet the operation of the whole air traffi ontrol network instead of a single airport. It will, however, give some idea of the potential gains that ould be realized systemwide. The Current System First, a simulation was made of the delay system that is urrently in use in flow ontrol. All flights were given the same priority and when ongestion ourred, flights were randomly delayed. This resulted in a mean delay time of 9.92 min a flight. (The mean delay time is the average delay per flight. The simulation, however, only gives delays in 15-min inrements. Some flights reeive no delays, whereas others are delayed in 15-min inrements.) Figure 1 gives the distribution of those delays; 25.7 perent of all flights reeived a delay of at least 15 min. Only 13 perent of the flights reeived a delay of more than 3 min and about.5 perent of the flights reeived a delay of more than 3 hr. rn " 4 3 2 a._ '" 1 o.j-----;f----.---+---+-=======t---. 3 6 9 12 15 18 Minutes of Delay FIGURE 1 Perentage of flights with delays exeeding X min, urrent system. FAA figures show that in 1986, flights at O'Hare were atually delayed an average of 11.34 min eah. Thus the simulation seems to somewhat underestimate delays at O'Hare. This is expeted beause the simulation does not aount for delays while the plane is taxiing, having mehanial work, and so on. Some, inluding ATA, argue that even FAA figures are too low beause they only measure delays of 15 min or more and do not inlude delays aused by airraft arriving late from

Mayer their previous stop. Even with these onsiderations, the simulation does seem to aount for most of the average delay. The time of the simulated delays was alulated by using industrywide seating apaities for speifi airraft and individual airline load fators. This amounted to 16,264 passenger-hr a day, or almost 6 million hr a year. Assuming that travelers' time is worth $1 an hour, the total amounts to about $6 million a year. This is only a onservative estimate of lost passenger time and does not inlude any osts of delays to the airlines, to those waiting for late passengers, or to any other parties involved. Some might argue that $1 an hour is too low. The osts an be easily resaled to another value of time. Using $15 an hour, the ost is almost $9 million a year. A "Maximum Effiieny" System Considered next was how the foregoing situation might hange if some priority system were implemented. Initially the flights were divided into four lasses depending on the size of the airraft involved. (Large jets were in the first lass, "streth" 727s and MD8s were in the seond lass, all smaller jets were in the third lass, and the rest of the planes were plaed in the fourth lass.) This lassifiation sheme by no means implies that this is how it should be established administratively. Rather, it approximates what it is believed a market-based aution of priorities would produe. In the simplest terms, the bigger airplanes with more passengers should be able to demand the most prompt sheduling, and hene would likely end up with the highest priorities. When ongestion ourred in the simulation, flights were delayed by their lass, rather than by random fators. That is, Class 1 flights were released before Class 2 flights, whih were still in front of flights in Class 3, and so on. Within a given lass, flights were treated equally. Flights were never able to hange lasses, no matter how long they were delayed. This is Plan A. The results of the simulation of Plan A were quite interesting. The mean delay time of 9.92 min stayed the same beause there were no hanges in apaity. The distribution of delays, however, showed signifiant hanges from the urrent system. Figure 2 shows that, overall, only 16 perent of the flights reeived delays of at least 15 min. However, these delays were longer and more onentrated. This is shown in the distribution by lass in Figure 3. Class 1 flights ran virtually on time, reeiving delays less than.1 perent of the time. Class 2 flights did almost as well, with 6 perent of the flights reeiving any delay. Only 2 perent of Class 2 flights reeived delays of at least 3 min, and virtually no flights reeived delays of 45 min or longer. Classes 3 and 4 did signifiantly worse, with 21 and 46 perent of their flights, respetively, reeiving delays of at least 15 min. Class 4 was hit the hardest, with 15 perent of its flights reeiving delays of over an hour and 8 perent of its flights reeiving delays of over 3 hr. Figure 4 shows the average delay per flight by lass. As might be expeted, Class 1 flights were delayed, on average, for less than.1 min. Class 2 flights were delayed an average of 1. 8 min, and Class 3 and 4 flights were delayed an average of 7.8 and 39.4 min, respetively. Rather than have small planes wait all day, airlines would have a great inentive to reshedule lower-lass flights. 5 4 a: 3 O> a.. 2. :j I I I I I 3 6 9 12 15 18 Minutes of Delay FIGURE 2 Perentage of flights with delays exeeding X min, Plan A. Cl 5 4 3 2 a.. 1... - Class 1.. -.. Class 2.. -- Class 3 - Class 4 17 o._...::==it==i=- --........... -........-1-=-.......... +.. -.. -.. -.. 1--l 3 6 9 12 15 18 Minutes of Delay FIGURE 3 Perentage of flights with delays exeeding X min, Plan A, by lass. (/) :; :::::;; 4 3 2 1 All One Two Three Four Flight Class FIGURE 4 Average delay time by lass, Plan A. When the delay time of this system is alulated, however, it is 7,14 passenger-hr a day, or about $2.6 million hr annually, whih is more than half of the delay under the urrent system. Again at $1 an hour that amounts to an annual passenger savings of $34 million. The large deline ours beause this plan onentrates delays on the smaller airraft with fewer passengers.

18 TRANSPORTATION RESEARCH RECORD 1161 Four Other Plans: Allowing Planes To Change Class Those who live in smaller ommunities or travel by smaller airraft ould well argue that Plan A is not equitable and would rowd smaller planes out of the system. Although an aution might alloate some higher priorities to airlines that use smaller airraft, in general it would be diffiult for a smaller ommuter airline to outbid its larger ounterparts. It is possible to devise plans that afford airraft in lower lasses some protetion. The trade-off is that as the lower lasses get more protetion, there are smaller redutions in delays. Four suh plans to provide this protetion were tested. These shemes provide ways for airraft in lower lasses to automatially jump their priority, depending on the length of their delay. Plan B, the stritest of these plans, allows airraft to inrease their priority by one lass every 6 min; Plan C allows this every 45 min; Plan D, every 3 min. The most lenient sheme, Plan E, allows a lass upgrade every 15 min. Again, within a lass, all flights are treated equally. Th a;;l:s vf it 5 ii11-u1a.liv1 WU1 su.a.iki1uurwttru anu signifiant. The mean delay is a onstant 9.92 in all the plans. The differene in delay distribution between lasses, however, dereases as the plans get more lenient. In Plan B, whih is desribed in Figures 5-7, Class 1 flights reeive muh the same treatment as in Plan A. In eah ase, Class 1 flights arry essentially a guarantee of on-time performane. However, the results hange more signifiantly for Class 2 and 3 flights, whih are muh better off in Plan A than Plan B. Class 2 flights reeive worse treatment, with their mean delay time almost tripling and the frequeny of their delays almost doubling. Class 3 average delay and frequeny of delay also inrease, although not by the same magnitude as for Class 2. Flights in Class 4, however, do signifiantly better, with the mean delay time dropping almost one-third This trend ontinues in Plans C, D, and E. Figures 8 and 9 summarize this information, showing how the results hange for eah lass of flights from the previous plan. A few generalizations beome apparent. From Plan B to Plan E, both the mean delay time and frequeny of delay for Class 1 inrease almost 2 perent with eah suessive plan (i.e., Class 1 servie beomes less guaranteed). Class 2 flights suffer smaller perentage losses between suessive plans, so that by Plan E, they are similar to Class 1 flights. Class 3 flights show O> 4 3 i: 2 1.j -;---f----f---+----t-========if==--+ j 3 6 9 12 15 18 Minutes of Delay FIGURE 5 Perentage of Hlghts with delays exeeding X min, Plan B. 5 4.. \ Cl 3.. \... u... 2. -. 1... 3.. 6 9 Minutes of Delay - Class 1 -Class 2 Cla ss 3 +--- Cl ass 4 - -.. 12 15 FIGURE 6 Perentage of Hlghts with delays exeeding X min, Plan B, by la... "' :;., :; "'.!: 3 ::::i; 2 1 All One Two Three four flight Class FIGURE 7 Average delay time by lass, Plan B. 6 5. 4 3 2........._.......-..._. 1.... A - Class 1 -Class 2... Class 3 - Class 4 B E F'.rioriti:z:ation Plqn FIGURE 8 Average delay per Hight. very little hange between plans. Their mean delay time shows a slight derease, but they are delayed more frequently. Class 4 flights show signifiant gains in mean delay time with eah suessive plan, but are still delayed with the same frequeny. Most of these gains are at the expense of Class 1 and 2 flights. Delays Versus Costs: What Is the Optimal Protetion for Lower Classes? As might be expeted, the more lenient the plan, the greater its annual ost of delays. (The annual delay osts for all plans and 18

Mayer 19 O'I "' 6 7 6 5 4., "' "- 3 2 1 A 8 - Class 1 -Closs 2 Class 3 -- Class 4 D E Prioritization Pion -..... FIGURE 9 Perentage of flights delayed 15 min or more, by lass. 3 "' O> (/) "' 2 (/) "- (/) 1,g :::; Current A 8 D E Prioritization Pion FIGURE 11 Annual number of on-time arrivals at O'Hare International Airport by plan. for the urrent system are shown in Figure 1. To determine hours of delay, divide by 1.) Figure 1 raises the interesting question of how muh soiety might be willing to give up (in delays) to have a more "equitable" system. That question will not be addressed here, although it may be noted that even the most lenient sheme (Plan E) provides for annual savings at a single airport of about $8 million or a derease amounting to 15 perent of the ost of delays. The striter plans do muh better; Plan B uts the annual ost of delays by 35 perent, or $2 million. The greatest savings is ahieved by Plan A, whih uts osts over 55 perent, or over $34 million. 6 5.2 4 Ci 3 (/).2 'i 2 1 Current A 8 D E Prioritization Pion FIGURE 1 Annual passenger delay osts at O'Hare International Airport by plan. Another way to measure the gains by a priority sheme is to look at how many passengers arrive on time (see Figure 11). With the urrent system, the simulation predits about 27 million on-time arrivals. With Plan A, that number inreases 23 perent to about 34 million. Even Plan E results in 3 million more on-time arrivals than the urrent system. It may be pointed out that it is important to have at least one lass of flights run virtually delay free. Presumably, there is a signifiant number of people whose Lime, espeially while on business travel, is muh more valuable Lhan $1 an hour. Even if less stringent plans are onsidered, safeguards should be built in to ensure that Class 1 servie is always exlremely reliable. These safeguards might protet Class l by limiting its size or how fast flights an be moved up to Class 1. This brings up the possibility of ombining some of these plans to ahieve an optimal one. For example, Plans A and E ould be merged so that flights might be allowed to move one lass every 15 min, but never into Class 1. Other similar ombinations are possible to determine a system that fits in with the overall poliy goals of the FAA. The Long-Run: What Is Missing? On further thought, it may be suggested that this simulation signifiantly underestimates the gains from adopting one of these plans. The simulation does not address the potential savings to airlines. A priority sheme that makes delays more preditable would signifiantly improve planning, leading to more effiient uses of apital and labor. Better information would also allow airlines to get more use out of gates, ground personnel, and equipment, whih are often sare resoures. They would be able to use their larger and more valuable airraft with greater frequeny, handling more passengers and argo. They ould potentially math their highest-rated okpit rews with their best-inslrurnented planes, reating flights that would be even less suseptible to weather delays. Beause planes with larger rews would reeive fewer delays, rews ould fly more flights a month. Costs per available seat should fall. Most important, it would give airlines muh greater ontrol over their timeliness. This ould permanently hange the way airlines do business. They would realize that under Plan D, for example, Class 1 flights have a 98.5 perent hane of running on time and the average delay is only 1.3 min. If the airlines were able to do their part to redue delays (e.g., by reating more realisti shedules and reduing mehanial problems), they would be able to ompete on timeliness in addition to servie and prie. Airlines ould advertise these different lasses of flights and their differing abilities to be on time, giving onsumers a greater variety of flying options. (Eastern Airlines already advertises the on-time performane of its Boston-New York Washington, D.C., shuttle. Imagine how many more shuttles, express flights, and so on, might develop if airlines had better ontrol of sheduling.) Preditable timeliness and more aurate flight times would relieve muh publi dissatisfation with the system, taking pressure away from the FAA and Congress.

2 The FAA would be able to onentrate more on safety and inreasing apaity and less on poliing the airlines. A priority system would have varying effets on airports. There are essentially two types of airports-those with one hub airline and those with either two hub airlines or none. At an airport dominated by one airline, delays often result beause that airline attempts to have all its flights arrive at one time and leave half an hour later. A priority system would fore that airline to reognize that this is impossible. Instead, the airline would have the inentive to write a more realisti shedule and ould enfore a priority system among its flights during bad weather. Other airlines at that airport would be able to ompete with the dominant arrier by bidding for priorities in an anonymous aution. At airports without one dominant airline, the priority system gets around the "oversheduling externality." Often airlines shedule flights at ongested times for ompetitive reasons, knowing that these flights will be delayed. A system of priorities redues this problem, giving airlines a better idea of how to shedule at these airports. The simulation does not aount for the seondary hanges that would our if a priority system were implemented beause it does not differentiate between airraft of the same size. To assume that all airraft have the same load fators and a single type of passenger is to understate the potential for gain. It is likely that the optimal use of a priority system is to serve markets with a variety of different lasses of servie. Currently, passengers on the same airraft are mixed as to the value of their time. If an airline were able to have express servie for passengers with a high value of time and regular servie for other passengers, it ould prie these servies aording to the various passengers' willingness to pay. The airlines would make more profits, and onsumers would have greater hoie of servie at varying pries. A look at the breakdown of flights at O'Hare shows that this segregation is possible, but very hard to predit. There is a great disrepany in osts, even between Plan B and the optimal Plan A ($38.8 million versus $25.6 million), beause of the large number of flights in Class 2. (See Figure 12 for a breakdown of the number of flights in eah lass.) The differene between the two plans is that the average delay for Class 2 roughly triples from Plan A to Plan B. A derease in osts ould be realized by dividing Class 2 into different groups depending on the value of individual flights in that group. These gains would be inreased further by inreasing the number of lasses. How Many Classes? These simulations, however, do not determine the optimal number of priorities. The use of four priority lasses was arbitrary based on a natural split of the types of airraft used at O'Hare. The hoie of how many priority lasses to use and how large eah should be will have a profound impat on the gains realized by eah priority sheme. The problem here is a trade-off between eonomi gain and omplexity. Presumably the largest gain would our if eah flight were given a priority based on its value of time, meaning that the number of lasses would equal the number of flights. This, however, would be very hard to implement. To fully utilize an airport, a onstant 5 4 3 :!: "'...._ 2 1 TRANSPORTATION RESEARCH RECORD 1161 One Two Three Four Flight Class FIGURE 12 Number of Hlgbts per lass. flow of traffi is essential. Speifially, the more preise a priority system gets, the harder it is to ensure a steady flow of ua.iii. Bt.;4.;iiUSC ur ii.us, ii. :)ysicaj.i \iiili a. r!o.i-v\:l;- ow.ull uw.ur of lasses (e.g., four) using moderate time bloks (e.g., 15 min) may be feasible. No attempt is made here to determine the optimal number of lasses and inrements of time. It is suggested, however, that it ould be possible to find a feasible system that had even larger gains than those that have been shown. IMPLEMENTATION ISSUES The priority system is ompletely ompatible with any enhanements to the urrent air traffi ontrol system. If the system apaity were inreased in some way (by hiring more ontrollers, building more runways or airports, using updated tehnology, et.), a priority system would use the additional apaity in the most effiient way. Use of Competition To Stop the Bunhing of Flights A priority system might also restruture the way airlines use resoures suh as runways and others. Currently there is a "Cath 22" in whih airlines see that bunhing flights auses delays, but are ompetitively unable to stop the bunhing, espeially while using a hub-and-spoke system. A priority system would solve this dilemma beause it orders the importane of flights at any given time. An airline might be hesitant to shedule a Class 4 flight at a time when many Class 1 and 2 flights are sheduled, knowing that the Class 4 flight would always be released last. This is a ompetitive method for enouraging the smoothing out of the shedule of flights without relying on relaxed antitrust standards, the urrent approah. It does not arbitrarily set the number of slots at an airport either, but instead allows the market to deide. Earlier in the paper the politial problems assoiated with many of the proposed solutions for air traffi ongestion were noted. The priority system has the potential to benefit all parties involved and thus would be politially feasible. However, some further elaboration might be needed, espeially how the priorities might be distributed.

Mayer Effiient and Equitable Alloation of Priorities No matter whih plan is hosen, the priorities involved have great value. The same problem ame up when the FAA introdued slot ontrol at four airports. There was debate as to who should own the slots and the duration of any property rights that were giveil The FAA deided to divide the slots into different groups: ommerial servie, ommuter servie, and "essential" servie, inluding international flights, private users, and so forth. Slots were numbered and the owners were given lifetime property rights, provided that the slots were regularly used and were not transferred between groups (e.g., ommuter slots were not to be used for larger ommerial servie). The slots ould be revoked by the FAA either for nonuse or in a random, predetermined order if the FAA needed them for another purpose. In a highly ontroversial move, the FAA gave slots to their urrent users rather than autioning them to the highest bidder. This allowed the airlines, not the publi or the airports, to generate the "sarity rents" at slotontrolled airports (6). The distribution of priorities also involves many of the same issues. Any system of distribution must ensure that new arriers have the means to obtain priorities and that no user is able to monopolize them, either in a given market or on a single route. It is also important that the priorities end up in the hands of the arriers that would use them most effiiently. The priorities must have a long enough duration to allow their owners to establish a profitable and onsistent business strategy. Finally, the publi should reeive the revenue from the sale of these priorities. A Repeated Aution It is reommended that the FAA distribute the priorities using a revised "Clarke tax," also referred to as a "repeated aution" (7). The repeated aution is a multistage proess that is not finished until eah bidder is satisfied with the results. The first stage of the aution involves soliiting a list of bids from the various players for eah of the priorities (or lasses) available. This ould be done simultaneously for eah of the airports in question. Then the ommissioner of the aution gathers all bids and awards the priorities to the highest bidders at the prie of the highest losing bid. That is, if there were 25 Priority 1 slots available at O'Hare at 9: a.m., they would be awarded to the 25 highest bidders at the prie of the 26th-highest bid. If there are fewer bidders than priorities for a given time, all bidders reeive those priorities at no ost. Limits ould be set up to ensure that no one is able monopolize any subset of the priorities. The ommissioner then publishes an anonymous list of bids and gives eah player a list of his winning bids. The players would have a speified period of time to evaluate their positions and hange any of their bids. If there are no hanges, the ommissioner delares the bidding losed and the awards are final. Otherwise, the ommissioner would take the revised bids and, using the same method as he did in Stage 1, hand out the results of Stage 2. This proess would ontinue until there were no hanges or the ommissioner delared that there were no major hanges and losed the aution. This sheme would get around the ompliated "system" problem of the simultaneous distribution of priorities at more than one airport. Airlines need to know the priorities they would use in all their markets in order to set up a system of flights that onforms to a onsistent business strategy. That is, to set up a Class 1 flight line, airlines need Class 1 priorities at all the airports on the line in order to preserve the full benefits of Class 1 operation. Eah round of bidding would inrease the information available to the airlines and give eah an opportunity to set up a business strategy based on market onstraints. Some arriers might not be willing to bid muh for high-priority slots, whereas other arriers would be willing to pay more for priorities, depending on their business strategy and their pereived value of that priority. No arriers ould gain by overbidding or underbidding, beause they might be fored to pay too high a prie for a priority or they might not reeive a priority at a prie they found profitable. This bidding system was tested by the FAA when they were onsidering its use in alloating slots (8). They simulated its use in the "Airline Management Game," with five airlines having varying marketing strategies and somewhat overlapping routes. They found that a ompetitive, effiient equilibrium was reahed quikly and the market players reeived overall higher profits after the aution than before its use. One of the reasons the repeated aution was not used to distribute slots was probably pressure from the airlines, whih argued that being fored to buy slots that they previously reeived at no ost would result in higher tiket pries to the onsumer. However, priorities annot be given away to urrent holders, beause they do not exist. They are reated entities that have great value, but only if alloated to the most effiient users. [There is some debate whether an aution would guarantee the most effiient use of priorities (6, 9).] The priorities ould, of ourse, be randomly alloated among urrent users on a weighted basis and the owners given property rights. That might eventually lead to their purhase from the urrent owners by the most effiient users, but that is not assured. There is a solution to this dilemma that ould satisfy both the airlines and the onsumers. Congress ould lower the urrent 8 perent tax on tiket sales by an amount orresponding to the revenue raised by a repeated aution. Although the average tiket pries should remain the same (or possibly be lower beause of inreased airline effiieny), the distribution of tiket pries would reflet the more effiient market. Pries would be more losely tied to ongestion; that is, the more ongested the time of day and the airport, the higher the tiket prie would be. Disount fares would be lower for those willing to travel at off-peak times or to wait longer. Unrestrited aess to markets, one of the keystones of deregulation, and effiient use of priorities ould also be ensured by holding the repeated aution every 6 months. Between autions the owners ould be free to buy and sell their priorities or the ommissioner ould anonymously aept offers to buy and sell unwanted priorities. Exess priorities would be distributed on a first-<:ome, first-served basis. In addition. airlines ould still be free to add more flights to a ity, but these flights would be at the lowest priority level. This would give a rude approximation of the optimal amount of ongestion in a 21

22 given airport. When entering at the lowest priority, the added entrant reeives a muh greater share of the delay ost that his entry imposes on other users. Finally, the results of this aution would provide finanial information that would allow the FAA to determine the optimal invesunent in additional apaity. Commuter Fllghts: Where Do They Flt In? If ommuters were given a separate ategory of priorities and shielded from ompetition with other users, the gains from this plan would be signifiantly ut, if not permanently erased. Large jets would still be delayed, and small planes would operate on time. However, in a ompetitive environment, users with larger airraft would inevitably bid up the prie of most priorities above affordable levels for many ommuter airlines. To ompensate, these airlines might find it eonomial in all but the smallest ities to have a mix of servie that would ;nl'l11rl "::It ldi"llc'lt n.n 'h1rj.,.:ar_,...,..;,.,...;tu f11n'ht Tt u.rn.111'1 'h'.:lra tn..._.. --.. ---..._ - -.. r... J o...... -- - -- --..... imagine that priorities would be bid for stritly in terms of the size of airraft using the priority. Even assuming that ommuters would mostly fly on Class 4 flights, they would still reeive some benefits from a strit priority sheme. Most important, if ommuter airlines do not buy high-pried priorities, tiket pries should fall. Also, most of those ommuters who fly into large airports intend to ath onneting flights to other destinations. Currently, onneting at a major hub is an extremely unpreditable affair. More aurate timetables under a priority system would make onnetions easier. Commuter airlines would probably reshedule some of their flights to avoid major delays at many airports. Although impossible to simulate, suh a hange ould signifiantly redue the average delays for lower-priority servie. Flyers would be better able to make deisions about how long to allow for making onneting flights. This benefit would extend not only to ommuter passengers, but to all who travel by air. What About Other Users? Finally there is a onern about how to deal with other airport users, inluding those originating in foreign ountries, not sheduled, and in essential servie. International flights ould be given automati priority and be required to pay a prorated fee to operate at ertain times or even required to purhase Class 1 servie. Even though international flights are not harged, they still represent only a small proportion of flights at ongested airports and often use airraft large enough to require some priority for effiient operation. Unsheduled users, although representing a small perentage of flights at ongested airports, ould be treated like other users. When unsheduled flights file their flight plans, they ould be required to hoose a level of priority, pay a prorated fee for that priority, and be treated as any other user with the same priority. This would give them the same hoies as others, also ensuring that they fae the full ost of flying at a given time. Servie that the FAA deems "essential" would travel at any priority to whih it is assigned. CONCLUSION The Future TRANSPORTATION RESEARCH RECORD 1161 The potential gains from an administrative hange to a priority system appear substantial ompared with the osts involved in implementing the system, whih seem relatively minor. This simulation found passenger time savings of over 55 perent, or $34 million a year, at a single airport. These savings have a perpetuity value of $68 million, a figure that would inrease greatly if it inluded gains at all the airports in the system. Ontime arrivals ould inrease by about 23 perent, meaning that 6 million more passengers would arrive as sheduled. Furthermore, these alulations appear to underestimate the savings, not taking into aount savings to airlines, seondary shifts in passenger and airline behavior, and benefits from greater preditability. A priority system seems to have the potential to revolutionize the organization of the air traffi ontrol system, benefiting all who fly. It ould even redue the average delay time by reduing the bunhing of flights. Additional Researh Additional researh needs to be done, however, to get a better idea of the feasibility and potential gains from a priority system. A more detailed omputer simulation would be required to determine the speifis about feasibility and the effets on urrent and future market partiipants. Further analysis should explain how the sheme might fit into an entire system as opposed to a single airport. It is also neessary to have some idea of what business strategies might be possible and profitable with a priority sheme, inluding how ommuter airlines would operate. This analysis should inlude the effets on servie for different-sized ommunities. Researh might also determine the possibility of a spot market, in whih airlines would be permitted to trade priorities between speifi flights on a daily basis. After all, as the New York Times noted in an editorial (1), "Even under the best of irumstanes... it will take years for apaity to ath up with traffi. That is why it is essential to find market-based ways to make the existing system more effiient.... [The airline industry's] potential ought not be undermined by a Government that sl."ilply an't keep L11e planes moving." ACKNOWLEDGMENTS This researh was ompleted while the author was enrolled in the Publi Poliy Analysis Program at the University of Rohester, Rohester, New York. The author wishes to thank several people whose help was essential in ompleting this researh. Charles Phelps, Diretor of the Publi Poliy Program at the University of Rohester, was instrumental in helping the researh along. His help was important in writing the simulation and he also provided suggestions in ritial areas of the projet. Larry Kiernan and Marv Olson of the FAA helped provide the data for the simulation and were available to provide omments on the diretion of the researh. Finally, Tom Burnard of TRB provided muh support for this projet and was always available to answer questions.

Mayer Any errors are, of ourse, the responsibility of the author. Comments on this paper would be muh appreiated. Finally, the author wishes to thank the FAA for providing finanial support for this researh and TRB for administering the Graduate Researh Award Program. REFERENCES 1. W. Chaze and W. Cook. The Late, Late Show. U.S. News and World Report, De. 27, 1986, p. 14. 2. B. Bean, B. Morris, and T. Smilh. Huny Up And Wait: Airllne Delays Bring Gripes-And Lots of Exuses. Wall Street Journal, April 28, 1987, p. 37. 3. J. Kotn and J. Valente. Cosmeti Change: Airlines' Pledge To Redue Delays May Be illusory. Wall Street Journal, Sept. 3, 1987, p. 21. 4. C. May. Six Airlines Agree To Redue Delays At 4 Big Airports. New York Times, Aug. 29, 1987, p. 1. 5. J. Dahl and T. Petzinger. Numbers Game: Continental Air Opens Data War. Wall Street Journal, Ot. 6, 1987, p. 31. 6. S. Kreager. Airline Deregulation and Airport Regulation. Yale Law Journal, Vol. 93, 1983, pp. 319-339. 7. T. N. Tideman,and G. Tullok. A New and Superior Proess for Making Soial Choies. Journal of Politial &onomy, Vol. 84, No. 6, 1986, pp. 1145-1159. 8. M. L. Balinski and F. M. Sand. The Alloation of Runway Slots by Aution. Report FAA-AVP-8-3. Offie of Aviation Poliy, FAA, U.S. Department of Transportation, 198. 9. S. Borenstein. On the Effiieny of Competitive Markets for Operating Lienses. Quarterly Journal of &onomis, 1988. 1. Waiting, Waiting in the Flight Line. New York Times, De. 22, 1986, p. A22. 23